IBC Laws Blog

Revamping Antitrust for Digital Ecosystem: Towards a New Regulatory Paradigm – Shivam Saurabh 

The competitive environment has undergone a significant transformation as a result of the digital revolution, especially in the dynamic realm of online ecosystems. Conventional antitrust laws, which were developed in a different age, find it difficult to tackle the particular difficulties presented by powerful online platforms. These difficulties include the incumbents’ enormous data advantage, the winner required to guarantee a robust digital ecosystem that upholds user welfare and encourages fair competition. Preventive measures should take precedence over reactive efforts in a new regulatory strategy. Ex-ante regulation can proactively address any anti-competitive activities before they take root. Examples of such regulations include stronger merger controls and standards for data interoperability. Furthermore, maintaining unrestricted access to crucial platform features stops strong players from shutting off rivals. Data governance is also very important. Robust legislation pertaining to data privacy and mechanisms for data portability provide people authority over their data. This promotes equal playing fields where competition is focused on innovation and value generation rather than data hoarding, in addition to protecting users. It is hard to forecast the evolution of digital marketplaces. Innovation that has upended preconceived notions about the nature of future technology has been the driving force behind the digital revolution. This research aims to outline strategies for maintaining and enhancing that creative, dynamic unpredictability. The Panel’s proposals centre on creating policy responses that can adjust and promote healthy competition in ambiguous circumstances. They also call for the establishment of a digital markets unit that can collaborate with stakeholders to increase market predictability.

Revamping Antitrust for Digital Ecosystem: Towards a New Regulatory Paradigm

Shivam Saurabh 
3rd year, B.A. LL.B.(Hons.), Chanakya National Law University 
Introduction

Large tech businesses now dominate the economy in a new way thanks to the digital era. These behemoths, who go by the moniker “Big Tech,” have accumulated enormous influence by controlling data, internet platforms, and vital infrastructure. This dominance has brought to light worries about less customer choice, stifled competition, and potential harm to innovation. Antitrust laws that are appropriate for the digital age are thus becoming more and more necessary. These changes are meant to deal with the particular problems that Big Tech presents. Conventional antitrust rules, built for the industrial era, find it difficult to control these businesses.

Market share and rivalry within certain product categories have always been the main concerns of antitrust law. A network effect that strengthens power and makes it harder for new entrants to compete is created when supremacy in one area spreads to other areas in the digital age, such as search engines, social media, and operating systems. In order to enable a more complex evaluation of Big Tech’s influence, reforms are investigating methods to identify pertinent markets based on user behaviour and data ecosystems. The digital economy depends heavily on data, and Big Tech corporations frequently own enormous databases of consumer information. They can improve their algorithms, tailor user experiences, and maybe even hinder competition from smaller businesses that don’t have access to such extensive data sets thanks to this data advantage. In order to facilitate data portability and interoperability and enable users to move across platforms more readily, reforms are taking these aspects into consideration. Regulations pertaining to data ownership and access may also level the playing field for innovation.[1]

Historically, the main goal of antitrust assessments has been to stop mergers that would significantly lessen competition within a certain product category. Big Tech acquisitions, however, may enhance their broader ecosystem and data advantage rather than always leading to horizontal monopolies (dominating one product sector). Reforms are looking into methods to closely examine acquisitions that would not immediately lessen competition but might, in the long term, impede future innovation or diminish consumer choice. The use of algorithms in decision-making processes that impact users, such search results or news feed curation, is growing. These algorithms, however, have the ability to limit user exposure to opposing views and reinforce prejudices. Reforms are looking into methods to encourage algorithmic transparency, which would enable consumers to question biased results and comprehend how algorithms operate. Regulations may also be intended to stop algorithms from being employed in ways that are anti-competitive. Enforcing antitrust laws successfully typically requires specific knowledge due to the sheer scale and complexity of Big Tech businesses. Reforms are looking into methods to bolster antitrust enforcement organizations that have access to resources and knowledge in the digital space. Cooperation across many regulatory bodies with a focus on consumer protection and competition may also be necessary to handle the complicated nature of Big Tech dominance.[2]

The remainder of the paper is organized as follows to demonstrate how the new platform laws redefine the tenets of modern antitrust, so changing and advancing competition law.

In order to limit the economic influence of digital platforms, Section II gives an overview of the new rules that have been established or are currently being proposed in Germany, the United States (U.S.), the United Kingdom (U.K.), and the European Union (E.U.). The new platform regulations are explained in Section III in contrast to the traditional, consumer welfare-based, and monolithic understanding of competition law. This understanding holds that the ultimate goal of competition law is to ensure that consumers receive a better deal in the form of more choices, higher quality, new products, or lower prices.

An Overview concerning the Current Platform Regulations

A new species of behemoths has emerged as a result of the digital age: Big Tech corporations, who have enormous power over data, online marketplaces, and vital digital infrastructure. This dominance has sparked worries about fewer options for customers, less competition, and potential stifling of innovation. As a result, a flurry of “New Platform Regulations” is starting to take shape, with the goal of tackling the particular difficulties that Big Tech presents in the larger framework of antitrust changes. Conventional antitrust rules are ill-suited to successfully govern these digital behemoths since they were developed for a different industrial age. These new rules go beyond merely reflecting accepted ideas; rather, they constitute a paradigm shift. There are two key ways in which the new platform laws deviate from standard antitrust analysis in the platform designation process. Firstly, competition authorities are no longer formally required to designate relevant antitrust markets, even if the designation process requires them to identify specific industries in which the platforms operate. Second, competition authorities no longer need to formally conclude that the platforms occupy a dominant or monopolistic position, even if the scoping criteria are designed to identify platforms with significant and persistent market dominance.

The status of designated platforms and dominance/monopoly power do not always have to coincide, even if there may be some overlap. This is evident from the application of the German Competition Law 4.0 and the DMA to platforms that have not yet achieved a dominating position.[3] The regulation of unilateral conduct has extended beyond dominance/monopoly power, indicating the growing concern that traditional concepts of “dominance” or “monopoly” fail to take into account the fact that digital platforms may have significant “intermediation power” that enables them to harm competition, even though they do not hold a dominant position in a clearly defined relevant product market.[4]

Taking on the difficulties of the digital age is made easier with the passage of the New Platform Regulations. Through the implementation of user empowerment, algorithmic fairness, and future-focused acquisition scrutiny, these changes hold promise for fostering a more competitive and equitable digital environment. It is yet unclear what the precise specifics are and how successful they will be. It will take time to find the ideal balance between limiting the influence of Big Tech and encouraging the innovation that powers the digital economy. This new regulatory framework is an evolution that is required to guarantee everyone has access to a robust and healthy digital ecosystem.

Digital Market Competition

Competition is the main force behind economic activity. In terms of prices, quality, and innovation, consumer welfare is raised, millions of jobs are generated, and a sizable quantity of economic value is generated. No other economic incentive is as powerful as this one to achieve these advantageous results for every market participant. Competition encourages newcomers and gatekeepers to strengthen their financial positions and potential to provide better services to all parties involved. As in competitive market arrangements, incumbent businesses may choose not to engage in R&D, enhancing their ability to provide superior services when there is no competition.[5]

A. Insufficient Contestability Due to Issues with Structural Competition in Online Marketplaces

A few tech companies now dominate an age never seen before thanks to the digital revolution. This tendency, referred to as “weak contestability,” poses a special problem for antitrust legislation. Conventional antitrust laws are ill-suited to deal with the structural issues that arise in digital markets since they were created for markets with simple entrance and exit. Antitrust law is undergoing new improvements to address the issues raised by weak contestability. A crucial concern is the notion of network effects. Due to the dominance of one or two gatekeepers, the digital markets where basic platform services are offered are likewise very concentrated.

This level of market concentration isn’t just attributable to the gatekeepers’ organic and prosperous market results. Over the last 10 years, a significant number of acquisitions by gatekeepers has consolidated the digital marketplaces; the majority of these purchases have not been prohibited by national competition authorities, or “NCAs”[6]

 Network effects are the phenomenon wherein a digital platform gains value as more people join it. As a result, there is a self-reinforcing loop that makes it harder for new competitors to succeed. In order to combat this, antitrust authorities are looking into measures to encourage interoperability, which enables users to move between platforms with ease and carry their data with them. Smaller players would not have to face the initial challenge of having a user base tied into a competitor’s ecosystem thanks to this levelling the playing field. The dominance of Big Tech in the gathering and application of data presents another difficulty. These businesses have enormous amounts of customer data at their disposal, which they use to improve algorithms, customize user experiences, and eventually push out rivals with less extensive datasets. Ownership and mobility of data are the main topics of recent antitrust advances. Users ought to have more authority over their data, choosing who can gather it and how it will be utilized. Regulations may also require data sharing with rivals under some circumstances, resulting in a more balanced data environment.

Moreover, the notion of “killer acquisitions” has become a matter of worry. Large tech corporations may buy up smaller, more creative competitors—not so much to drive them out of a particular industry as to keep them from upsetting their wider ecosystem or future advances. In order to examine acquisitions more closely and evaluate their potential to inhibit future competition and innovation—even if they don’t immediately lead to market share dominance—new antitrust laws are being suggested.[7] It is also necessary to modify antitrust law enforcement for the digital era. It’s possible that traditional antitrust agencies lack the knowledge and resources necessary to successfully oversee the intricate digital marketplaces. Recent advances include looking into methods to provide enforcement agencies with specific knowledge and encourage cooperation with other regulatory authorities that prioritize consumer protection and competitiveness. This comprehensive strategy recognizes that Big Tech domination has many facets.[8]

B. Competition for Innovation and Competitive Behaviour

For antitrust policy makers, evaluating behaviour in the context of innovative competition presents a difficulty. As was said in the preceding section, both the conventional frameworks of perfect competition and imperfect competition may not apply to inventive competition. To do this, antitrust laws governing competitive behaviour must be changed. Economic frameworks that acknowledge non-price competition and technological development should be applied in antitrust policy. The welfare of consumers and economic efficiency are impacted by non-price components of competitive behaviour. Antitrust regulators must approach competitive behaviour with a dynamic viewpoint in order to address innovation competition. This section examines how rules for competitive conduct are impacted by innovative rivalry in transaction methods, product features, and manufacturing processes.

A new era of innovation has been brought about by the digital age, but it has also highlighted the shortcomings of antitrust laws that were created for an outdated industrial environment. This article examines the intricate relationship between innovation and competition and the difficulties it poses for the implementation of antitrust laws.

B.1 Innovation’s Engine of Progress: Advancements in technology have the potential to be a potent catalyst for economic expansion. With the help of new technology, entrepreneurs and small- to medium-sized businesses (SMEs) may upend existing markets and offer superior goods and services. Pioneering businesses may see speedier development as a result of the quick acceptance of new inventions, but existing businesses may also feel pressure to keep up with the times or risk being left behind. In the end, customers gain from this dynamic and competitive atmosphere that is fostered by the ongoing turnover.[9]

B.2 The Antitrust Assessment Challenge: Nonetheless, antitrust enforcement has difficulties due to innovation’s inherent characteristics. Conventional antitrust laws concentrated on competitive indicators that were visible in the near term, such price and market share rivalry. The consequences of innovation, however, might take years to materialize. For example, a new technology may seem to the established players disruptive at first, which causes them to fade away. Longer term, nevertheless, may see a more competitive environment with more options for customers. This broader picture may be overlooked by standard antitrust assessments using short-term indicators.[10]

B.3 The Disruption Dilemma: Innovation may have a disruptive quality by nature. As new technologies gain traction, they have the potential to replace older ones, which might cause fewer creative businesses to fail. Although this is a necessary component of development, antitrust authorities.[11]

B.4 Innovation and Market Dominance: Research and development (R&D) expenditures made by a dominant business can strengthen its position in the market. This encourages creativity but also raises questions about restricting competition. Utilizing its resources, a dominating actor may try to buy out prospective competitors or create technologies that restrict customer choice or access to vital information or platforms. Antitrust laws must make sure that innovation doesn’t get used as a means of gaining an unfair advantage.[12]

B.5 Learning from the Courts: The courts’ attempts to address competition and innovation are demonstrated by a number of well-known antitrust cases. The telecom case US v. AT&T emphasizes the possible advantages of permitting dominant businesses to set higher initial rates as it can spur further innovation that eventually helps customers. Conversely, the Microsoft antitrust case highlights how difficult it is to implement conventional antitrust rules in a quickly evolving technology environment. The court acknowledged that certain anti-competitive tactics may become outdated as a result of competition brought about by innovation. It also underlined how crucial it is to stop businesses from utilizing innovation to damage customers or restrict access.[13]

B.6 The Way Ahead- A Detailed Strategy: For antitrust enforcement to be effective in the digital age, it is imperative to go beyond a limited concentration on price competition and market share. The “rule of reason,” a more sophisticated strategy, is required. This strategy takes into account both the possible advantages of innovation and the possible disadvantages to competitiveness. Furthermore, a long-term outlook is crucial. Longer-term study is required to determine the real influence of a company’s activities on competition and innovation, as short-term indications may be deceptive. [14]

B.7 Striking a Balance: In the digital era, enforcing antitrust laws should ultimately aim to foster an atmosphere that promotes innovation while discouraging businesses from abusing it to gain an unfair competitive advantage and injure customers. This calls for a careful balancing act. A strong digital ecosystem that is built on innovation, fair competition, and a steady stream of fresh concepts and improved goods for customers can only be achieved by striking the correct balance.[15]

Conclusion

The competitive environment has undergone a significant transformation as a result of the digital revolution, especially in the dynamic realm of online ecosystems. Conventional antitrust laws, which were developed in a different age, find it difficult to tackle the particular difficulties presented by powerful online platforms. These difficulties include the incumbents’ enormous data advantage, the winner required to guarantee a robust digital ecosystem that upholds user welfare and encourages fair competition. Preventive measures should take precedence over reactive efforts in a new regulatory strategy. Ex-ante regulation can proactively address any anti-competitive activities before they take root. Examples of such regulations include stronger merger controls and standards for data interoperability. Furthermore, maintaining unrestricted access to crucial platform features stops strong players from shutting off rivals. Data governance is also very important. Robust legislation pertaining to data privacy and mechanisms for data portability provide people authority over their data. This promotes equal playing fields where competition is focused on innovation and value generation rather than data hoarding, in addition to protecting users. It is hard to forecast the evolution of digital marketplaces. Innovation that has upended preconceived notions about the nature of future technology has been the driving force behind the digital revolution. This research aims to outline strategies for maintaining and enhancing that creative, dynamic unpredictability. The Panel’s proposals centre on creating policy responses that can adjust and promote healthy competition in ambiguous circumstances. They also call for the establishment of a digital markets unit that can collaborate with stakeholders to increase market predictability.


References:

[1] Reshaping Digital Competition: The New Platform Regulations and the Future of Modern Antitrust, Elias Deutscher, Volume 67, Issue 2, https://journals.sagepub.com/doi/full/10.1177/0003603X221082742

[2] Antitrust Reform in the Digital Era: A Sceptical Perspective, Robert W. Crandall, Thomas W. Hazlett, https://businesslawreview.uchicago.edu/print-archive/antitrust-reform-digital-era-skeptical-perspective

[3] DMA Proposal, Articles 3 (6), 3 (1) (c), and 15 (4). Additionally, platforms that are not yet dominant are expressly covered by the new German Competition Law 4.0 (see supra note 1, s. 19a (2) 3).

[4]  Modernizing the Missbrauchsaufsicht for market-dominant companies, Project in the framework of the Federal Ministries of Water and Energy (BMWI), (2018), pp. 40–42  https://www.bmwi.de/Redaktion/DE/Publikationen/Wirtschaft/modernisierung-der-missbrauchsaufsicht-fuer-marktmaechtige-unternehmen.pdf?__blob=,publicationFile&v=15.

[5]The Digital Markets Act, as proposed by the Commission, op. cit., p. 8, para. 27.

[6] US Study on Digital Market Competition, op. cit., p. 38.

[7]Section I of the Impact Assessment Report, op. cit., p. 9, para 33.

[8] BLOOMBERG, July 1, 2019, Gerrit De Vynck, The Power of Google and Amazon Looms Over Tech IPOs, accessible at: https://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2019-07-01/google-s-and-amazon’s-power-loomsover-procession-of-tech-ipos.

[9] See Jacob Schmookler, ‘Bigness, Fewness, and Research’ (1959) 67 Journal of Political Economy 628; Jacob Schmookler, ‘Economic Sources of Inventive Activity’ (1962) 22(1) Journal of Economic History 1;

[10] Verizon Communications IncvLaw Offices of Curtis VTrinko, LLP, 540 US 398, 402 n 1 (2004) 407 (hereafter Trinko).

[11] ‘The structural approach, as applied by the District Court, is thus capable of fulfilling its purpose even in a changing market.’

[12] Einer Elhauge, ‘Defining Better Monopolization Standards’ (2003) 56(2) Stanford Law Review 253.

[13]“Better Late than Early: Vertical Differentiation in the Adoption of a New Technology,” by Prajit K. Dutta, Saul Lach, and Aldo Rustichini, 4(4) Journal of Economics & Management Strategy 563 (1995).

[14] In his book “New Studies in Philosophy, Politics, Economics, and the History of Ideas,” 10 (Marcellus S. Snow tr., 2002), Friedrich A. Hayek discusses “Competition as a Discovery Procedure” (1968) 5 Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics 9.

[15] Part 5 of Online Platforms and Market Power: Rivals in the Digital Economy Hearing held before the United States House Committee on the Judiciary, accessible at: https://docs.house.gov/meetings/JU/JU05/20200117/110386/HHRG-116-JU05-Wstate-BarnettD20200117.pdf,

Follow us

Don't be shy, get in touch. We love meeting interesting people and making new friends.